ظرفیت پذیرش نوآوری های انرژی در پرتغال: شواهد تاریخی و چشم انداز آینده /  The capacity for adopting energy innovations in Portugal: Historical evidence and perspectives for the future

 ظرفیت پذیرش نوآوری های انرژی در پرتغال: شواهد تاریخی و چشم انداز آینده  The capacity for adopting energy innovations in Portugal: Historical evidence and perspectives for the future

  • نوع فایل : کتاب
  • زبان : انگلیسی
  • ناشر : Elsevier
  • چاپ و سال / کشور: 2017

توضیحات

رشته های مرتبط  مدیریت و مهندسی صنایع
گرایش های مرتبط مدیریت نوآوری و فناوری 
مجله  پیش بینی فنی و تغییر اجتماعی – Technological Forecasting & Social Change
دانشگاه  لیسبون، پرتغال

نشریه  نشریه الزویر

Description

1. Introduction The deployment of new energy technologies in large scale is needed in the next decades in order to overcome current societal challenges (e.g. environmental problems, security of supply) (IPCC, 2014). Historical experience reveals that the emergence and diffusion of energy technologies are slow and marked by a series of barriers (Grubler et al., 2012; Grubler, 2012; Fouquet, 2012). One of the reasons for this slowness is the extent of institutional and organizational changes that are often necessary for the emergence and dissemination of a new technology (Bergek et al., 2008; Jacobsson; Bergek, 2011). However, the analysis of international patterns of technology diffusion shows an acceleration of growth as the technology moves from pioneer countries and reaches new regions (Grubler, 2012, 1998; Bento, 2013). A possible explanation for this empirical regularity is the presence of externalities (i.e., “spillovers”) from the technology development in pioneer countries, which supports its faster dissemination in subsequent markets (Jaffe, 2005; Perkins and Neumayer, 2005). The positioning of each country in the sequence of international diffusion depends on internal conditions, including the ability to absorb and use new technologies (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989, 1990). The adoption of foreign technology is a key element in the convergence of the less developed economies with more advanced countries (Fagerberg and Godinho, 2008; Godinho, 1995). The notion of “latecomer advantage” has been put forward to explain the technological dynamism of less advanced countries over more developed ones (Gerschenkron, 1962). It is argued that the technological backwardness of the former allows them to absorb the most recent innovations developed in the latter, without having to bear the high initial costs of development (Perkins and Neumayer, 2005). In addition, they are not encumbered by the so-called vintage capital, which is known to be a factor that delays the transition to new technologies in pioneer countries, by creating stranded costs due to the previous investments in human capital and infrastructure (Unruh, 2000; Clark and Wrigley, 1997; Frankel, 1955). This line of reasoning can explain why the transition to new energy systems tends to take less time in follower countries, which benefit from both the experience gained from the diffusion in pioneer countries and a cheaper technology (Grubler, 2012). Wilson (2009) shows evidence of the acceleration of diffusion in late adopters for several energy supply and end-use technologies. The marketing and management literature also finds the same effect of faster diffusion in countries that adopt a given product innovation later, what has been called the “lead-lag effect” (see a review in Peres et al., 2010). Portugal is an intermediate economy and a typical case of “follower” of technological changes initiated in the more advanced economies (Godinho, 2007; Godinho and Caraça, 1988). A few studies analyze the recent evolution of innovative and institutional capacity in Portugal (e.g. Conceição and Heitor, 2005; Fagerberg and Godinho, 2008). In general economic terms, there is evidence of convergence (i.e. “catching up”) with the most advanced economies, given the low initial levels of innovation as well as a growing dynamics in some areas (Lains and Silva, 2013; Lains, 2003). But, this process has been associated with a persistent deficit in the technological balance of payments, which can be seen as an indicator of investment in the adoption of foreign technology. This emphasizes the role of technology transfer1 in the convergence process (Godinho, 2007, 1995). In fact, technology transfer, in its various forms (trade, foreign direct investment or licenses), is an instrument that allows absorbing knowledge spillovers from abroad (Keller, 2010). However, the conditions that permit to absorb eventual spillovers and how the evolution of these conditions relates to the rate of diffusion more recently are still poorly understood, particularly in the case of energy technologies.
اگر شما نسبت به این اثر یا عنوان محق هستید، لطفا از طریق "بخش تماس با ما" با ما تماس بگیرید و برای اطلاعات بیشتر، صفحه قوانین و مقررات را مطالعه نمایید.

دیدگاه کاربران


لطفا در این قسمت فقط نظر شخصی در مورد این عنوان را وارد نمایید و در صورتیکه مشکلی با دانلود یا استفاده از این فایل دارید در صفحه کاربری تیکت ثبت کنید.

بارگزاری